stock options math

Learn a Simplified Synthesis of Financial Options Pricing

Estimated Read Time: 5 minute(s)
Common Topics: price, scholes, options, option, call

Financial options (the right to purchase (“call“) or sell (“put“) stock (or other assets)) at a fixed price at a future date have been around for a long time. They are attractive for the option buyer since his/her total risk is the premium (price) paid for the option, as contrasted with futures contracts which are obligations to buy a stock or commodity at a future date.  However, until recently, financial options pricing presented great difficulties and controversy: how do you put a fair price on an asset deliverable at a future date, sometimes years ahead?  Then in 1973 Drs. F. Black, M. Scholes, and  R.C. Merton published a model for options pricing based essentially on Gaussian (random-walk) probability.

The following is the famed Black-Scholes equation for determining the “fair” price of a call or put option.

Black-Scholes equation

Some of the  involved math may be gleaned from the following excerpt of its derivation:

Black-Scholes derivation

And finally the formula itself:

Black-Scholes formula

where c is the cost of a call option and p the cost of a put option. I  won’t discuss the remaining parameters since we won’t be using this model directly.

As a purely theoretical inquiry, what mathematics lies behind the Black-Scholes formula?  I have long wondered and marveled at its complexity.  After all, it’s supposedly based on Gaussian probability aka random walk. Certainly, the formula does not lend itself to a ready understanding of what lies behind rational options pricing.  Is there a simpler, more intuitive approach yielding the same quantitative results coupled with deeper insight into options pricing rationale?  I propose one herewith.

I am assuming a very basic familiarity with put and call options  All you need to know is the spot price, strike price, duration, and (annualized) volatility.   By “volatility” the financier specifically means the standard deviation of the spread of underlying stock prices over a 1 year period.    (Interest rate is usually another input and will be touched on later.)

At this point, I need to mention that the sole option price that has to be determined is the call price.  The put price for the same input parameters is immediately derivable from the so-called put-call parity rule, which is just (call price) – (put price) = (spot price) – (strike price).  So I will limit myself to call options.

Another thing to mention is that the below applies strictly speaking to so-called European options only; however, there is very little difference in price between these and so-called American options, usually well below 1%.  An online Black-Scholes options price calculator makes this clear.  Another easy-to-use Black-Scholes calculator for call options is at mystockoptions.com.

Let us go by way of an example.  Assume the spot price is $20 and the strike price $18; also that the volatility is $1 or 1/20 = 5% on a one-month basis (which is ##\frac 1 {\sqrt12}##of  the annualized volatility).  This means the mean is $20 and the standard deviation for 1 month of data is $1.    See fig. 1.

standard deviation one month

We will now develop the necessary data to determine the price of a 3-month call option. At three months the strike price will represent less than 2  std. deviations since the price structure will now be “spread out” by a factor of  ##\sqrt 3##.  The 3-month distribution will then look like fig.2.

 

3 month spot price distribution

Notably, the $18 strike price now represents not -2σ but -2/##\sqrt 3## = -1.15σ.  So the area under the probability density function to the right of that value represents the probability that the price will be > strike price after 3 months in which case the option has value.

But that is not the whole story.  The other question is “ok, but what will be the average value assuming the option does have value?  Clearly, we want the average of the x-axis to the right of the strike price, i.e. x adjusted such that at x = -1.15 the contract value is 0.

So let’s do some probability.  Let f(x) be the probability density function and F(x) the cumulative function, i.e. the area from -##\infty## to x.  The entire area = 1 so ##F(\infty)## = 1.  Then the average value of x such that F(-1.15) = 0 will be, noting that F(-x) = F(1-x),

$$ \bar x = \int_{-1.15}^{\infty} (x – (-1.15)) f(x) \, dx$$

$$ = 1.15\int_{-1.15}^{\infty} f(x) \, dx + \int_{-1.15}^{ \infty} x f(x) \, dx.$$

So what to do with the last integral?  No tables, nothing!  But we are saved by a very felicitous relation which is x f(x) = – f ‘(x)

so now we get

$$ \bar x = 1.15\int_{-1.15}^{\infty} f(x) \, dx  \text{} ~  –  \int_{-1.15}^{\infty} f ‘(x) \, dx.$$    or

$$ \bar x = 1.15F(1.15) – [(f(\infty) – f(1.15)] $$

= 1.15F(1.15) + f(1.15)

##\bar x ## = 0.875 + 0.206 = 1.212

Finally we multiply by the dollar value corresponding to ##\sqrt 3 ## to get cost c = ($1.73)(1.212) = $2.09.

Comparing this with the Black-Scholes calculator with the substitution ## \sigma_{1 yr} = \sqrt{(12/3)}\sigma_{3 mos.} ## to  annualize the volatility we get $2.09.  Exactly the same price as ours.

Let’s proceed with an out-of-the-money case, i.e. when the strike price is above the spot price.  For this I chose as follows:

spot = $20

strike = $25

1 month volatility = $2 = 1σ

duration = 3 mos.  See fig. 3.  This is very much an out-of-the-money option, obviously.

distribution pricing

The approach is the same:  the integration to obtain average x again starts at the σ equivalent of the strike price which will be ($25-$20)/2.5/1.73 = 1.44.  So to find the average x starting at 1.44 we need

$$\int_{1.44}^{\infty} (x – 1.44) f(x) \, dx$$ = f(1.44) – 1.44(1 – F(1.44)) = .142 – 1.44(0.075) = 0.034 x ($2 x 1.73) = $0.11 vs. $0.19 for the Black-Scholes model. Presumably, roundoff error accounts for the difference.

In general the price of any call option will be

$$ c = \left( \frac $ \sigma \right)  \int_{\sigma_{strike}}^{\infty} (x – \sigma_{strike}) f(x) \, dx $$

with ## \sigma = \sqrt{n/\sigma_v} ## , n the duration in years and ## \sigma_v ## = (annualized) volatility.

I further tested the model with spot = strike = $20, and got $0.69 which agreed exactly with the Black-Scholes calculation.

The prevailing interest rate should figure in these computations.  It’s easily taken care of by simply accounting for the “present value” of the payout.  The same can be said for inflation, which at this date (Aug. 2018) is actually greater than the “safe” short-term interest rate.

I’ve appended an excel file ## ^{(1)} ## that enables these computations for any combination of spot, strike, duration, and volatility.  (The program delineates between in-the-money and out-of-the-money cases).

Should this model be used for options pricing rather than the Black-Scholes?  No.  The latter has been assiduously nurtured over the decades and can allegedly handle more input parameters. Online calculators facilitate its application. The point of this investigation is rather to gain insight into options pricing mathematics by formulating a much-simplified basis of evaluating options, based on Gaussian variation like the Black-Scholes model, yet yielding the same results as the latter model in a much more understandable way.

Then too, how valuable is any model based on random theory really?  The infamous collapse of the hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management in 1999, in which Dr. Scholes was a participating investor, answers that question nicely, as does the 2008 general financial collapse.  I recommend reading N. Taleb’s The Black Swan for casting further doubt on the predictability of any stochastic future pricing models.  He shows that there can be and usually are severe bumps on those cherished smooth Gaussian curves!

Resources:

(1) Copy of rude man call option calculator

Additional (duplicate) ppt slides for the three embedded figures.  These are of better quality than the embodied ones:   blk-sch.ppt

 

 

19 replies
  1. bhobba says:
    rude man

    Agreed. But I question even the "get-rich-slowly" postulate. The only way to get rich is to cheat, like front-running and insider trading, which successful hedge funds obviously do. No other way could they beat odds of 2% per annum management and 20% of profits.
    After all, it is a zero-sum game in relation to the S&P averages. Minus the transaction costs you point out.One can reduce management costs by using indexed funds that are low cost, and then there is the use of a geared fund. They are very volatile but if you regularly put money in (hard during market downturns – you need to have faith in contrarian investing) that volatility works for you in the form of dollar cost averaging. Or you can do contrarian investing eg
    https://p8s8a2t3.stackpathcdn.com/wp-content/uploads/2015/04/The-Zone-System-research-paper.pdf

    But regularly getting returns above the index, while possible, is not that much above it – I think your 20% return on the average is pretty much the max. But compounding $1000 pm at 20% for 20 years you get $2,240,256.00. As I said – get rich slowly. A few can do better such as Simons – but they are rare and closely guard how they do it.

    Thanks
    Bill

  2. BWV says:

    So Black Scholes is not perfect because you can’t perfectly dynamically hedge as the model requires and returns aren’t normal. In practice the fat tails and skew are represented with a volatile smile where deep out of the money puts have higher vol than at the money.

    https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Volatility_smile

    So in physics if you have a model where energy is conserved then it may or may not be right, but if it violates the conservation of energy it is definitely wrong. In finance, the absence of arbritrage is a similar constraint – if you model allows free money then it is definitely wrong. Any option model that uses some guess as to the expected return of the stock as a discount rate will lead to arbitrage and is therefore wrong.

  3. rude man says:
    DrDu

    When I first heard about the Black Scholes theory, it was formulated in therms of stochastic or Ito-integrals, which are quite unfamiliar to physicists. The excerpt from the derivation which you show seems to use some bracket formalism a la QM. Could you provide a source?I think you have as good a shot at that as I would. I just googled black-scholes and picked the most elaborate math I could find. The idea behind that was of course to show that complete black-scholes formulas are pretty daunting which prompted me to this simpler approach.

    All such formulas are of course approximations and subject to gross errors – the human mind is not analyzable by math!

    bhobba

    Nice – its something everyone should know about – but only a few ever will – which is a pity.

    Yes – as was aluded to in the article and related to it being 'wrong' due to the phenomena of fat tails – which is deeply rooted in the central limit theorem that you need to really understand to know why the beautiful math is actually a chimera. Mandelbrot and others warned about it:
    https://users.math.yale.edu/mandelbrot/web_pdfs/mildvswild.pdf

    Again, as alluded to in the insights article, it is also is heavily implicated in the 2008 market crash:
    https://www.amazon.com/Misbehavior-Markets-Fractal-Financial-Turbulence/dp/0465043577

    Just as an aside, and I think mentioned in the book above, when Mandelbrot was a young researcher at IBM some guy came up with a sure fire way to make money from the stock market. They ran simulation after simulation – it never failed. But to be sure they handed it over to Mandelbrot who saw the problem immediately – they didn't account for transaction costs – when they did – it failed.

    I am unsure to give as the reason why people should know about it as its foolish application despite warnings from very distinguished mathematicians like Mandelbrot, or the actual beautiful, but flawed math itself. Maybe both – it is often said in markets there is no get rich scheme – only get rich slowly. If you think you have found one it likely contains a flaw like you didn't consider transaction costs or the assumptions the central limit theorem is based on.

    Thanks
    BillAgreed. But I question even the "get-rich-slowly" postulate. The only way to get rich is to cheat, like front-running and insider trading, which successful hedge funds obviously do. No other way could they beat odds of 2% per annum management and 20% of profits.

    After all, it is a zero-sum game in relation to the S&P averages. Minus the transaction costs you point out.

  4. BWV says:

    Another way to think about why the risk free rate is used without regard to the expected return of the stock:

    Suppose I can borrow and lend at the risk free rate (any additional interest rate spread for credit risk can be added without changing this).

    I want to enter into a contract requiring me to purchase stock XYZ at time t2 in the future. What is the discount price of this contract?

    So let St be today’s stock price and D the discount factor to time t2 (so if the risk free rate is 5% D would be 1.05 if the time to t2 is one year).

    It cost me St to buy stock XYZ now. The purchase price of XYZ at t2 is St*D if enter I enter into an irrevocable contract today to buy the stock at time t2. If the contract price is less than St*D I can sell the contract, short the stock today, invest the proceeds, earning the risk free rate and have a zero capital required, risk free return of St*D-contract price. If the contract price is too high, just reverse the trade for the same effect

    Options on XYX with expiration date t2 just involves selling or buying portions of the XYZ’s return distribution between now and t3 – so the risk free return remains the appropriate discount rate

  5. BWV says:

    Great points and a good exposition in the referenced article

    If you forget about the model, interest rates, inflation, the beta and risk premium for the stock, put-call parity has to hold, otherwise free money is available in the financial markets

    It gets expressed a number of ways but simplistically, and ignoring discount factors it is
    Stock – cash = call – put

    Which conceptually means that a long position in the stock can be replicated with an at – the -money call and put. Because you can use one side to hedge the other if this relationship is violated, the risk premium for stocks cancels out and the only relevant discount factor is the risk-free rate, which incorporates inflation expectations

  6. bhobba says:
    DrDu

    When I first heard about the Black Scholes theory, it was formulated in therms of stochastic or Ito-integrals, which are quite unfamiliar to physicists. The excerpt from the derivation which you show seems to use some bracket formalism a la QM. Could you provide a source?I have seen a couple myself – but they from recollection all seemed to require Ito's Lema:
    https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Itô's_lemma

    Evidently though there are a lot of derivations about that take different routes, one from the equation of Brownian Motion:
    http://www.newsmth.net/bbsanc.php?path=/groups/sci.faq/FE/fe/M.1220512433.t0&ap=253

    Thanks
    Bill

  7. bhobba says:

    Nice – its something everyone should know about – but only a few ever will – which is a pity.

    alan2

    But of course, we know that option pricing doesn't actually work. Just like MPT and CAPM it is fun math but it doesn't reflect reality.Yes – as was aluded to in the article and related to it being 'wrong' due to the phenomena of fat tails – which is deeply rooted in the central limit theorem that you need to really understand to know why the beautiful math is actually a chimera. Mandelbrot and others warned about it:
    https://users.math.yale.edu/mandelbrot/web_pdfs/mildvswild.pdf

    Again, as alluded to in the article, it Is also is heavily implicated in the 2008 market crash:
    http://web.mit.edu/wangj/www/pap/HW_070228.pdf

    I am unsure to give as the reason why people should know about it as its foolish application despite warnings from very distinguished mathematicians like Mandelbrot, or the actual beautiful, but flawed math itself.

    Thanks
    Bill

  8. DrDu says:

    When I first heard about the Black Scholes theory, it was formulated in therms of stochastic or Ito-integrals, which are quite unfamiliar to physicists. The excerpt from the derivation which you show seems to use some bracket formalism a la QM. Could you provide a source?

  9. andrewkirk says:
    rude man

    First you say inflation is incorporated into interest rates, then you they're not comparable.No, I didn't say the second. I said that past inflation is not comparable with future interest rates. There is a relationship between inflation expectations and interest rates but we need to compare them for the same period.

  10. rude man says:
    andrewkirk
    rude man

    current safe short-term interest rates are far below inflation. The former about 1.5%, the latter close to 4%. I don't know which economy you're referring to, or which inflation measure, but all the inflation measures I know of* are about what has happened in the recent past, whereas interest rates relate to what is expected in the future. So the two are not comparable.

    The Black-Scholes option pricing formula is based on the construction of an arbitrage with a dynamic hedging portfolio that replicates the performance of the option. Inflation doesn't need to be considered because, regardless of what inflation does, the hedging portfolio will replicate the value of the option, and the value of a particular hedging portfolio can be explicitly observed based only on current stock prices and interest rates.

    * Other than the expected-inflation component of the yield on an inflation-linked bond. But those bonds are unusual and I doubt that is what the 4% relates to."I don't know which economy you're referring to, or which inflation measure, but all the inflation measures I know of* are about what has happened in the recent past, whereas interest rates relate to what is expected in the future. So the two are not comparable."
    ??? They don't change that fast!
    If I pay x$ at t=0 and cash in at t=1 year, the inflation will very probably be very much at t=1yr as at t=0.

    ence https://www.physicsforums.com/insights/a-simplified-synthesis-of-financial-options-pricing/

  11. andrewkirk says:
    rude man

    current safe short-term interest rates are far below inflation. The former about 1.5%, the latter close to 4%. I don't know which economy you're referring to, or which inflation measure, but all the inflation measures I know of* are about what has happened in the recent past, whereas interest rates relate to what is expected in the future. So the two are not comparable.

    The Black-Scholes option pricing formula is based on the construction of an arbitrage with a dynamic hedging portfolio that replicates the performance of the option. Inflation doesn't need to be considered because, regardless of what inflation does, the hedging portfolio will replicate the value of the option, and the value of a particular hedging portfolio can be explicitly observed based only on current stock prices and interest rates.

    * Other than the expected-inflation component of the yield on an inflation-linked bond. But those bonds are unusual and I doubt that is what the 4% relates to.

  12. rude man says:

    “Inflation doesn’t need to be explicitly accounted for in pricing options because it is automatically incorporated into the interest rate and hence also the expected growth rate.”

    Not so. As I said, current safe short-term interest rates are far below inflation. The former about 1.5%, the latter close to 4%.

  13. andrewkirk says:
    rude man

    The Black-Scholes model also ignores expected growth, at least the on-line calculators do.It doesn't ignore expected growth. It assumes that the stock will grow at a rate equal to the risk-free interest rate minus the dividend rate (or other net benefits of holding the assets). The reasoning behind that assumption is the main insight that the original Black-Scholes paper introduced. Discussing it is beyond the scope and purpose of your note, but I think it is important to acknowledge that growth is not ignored but rather assumed to be at that rate.

    The expected growth cancels out against the discounting of the payout on maturity, leaving a discount factor on the first term in the formula that is ##e^{-uT}## where ##T## is time to option maturity and ##u## is the dividend rate. In examples where the underlying asset has negligible dividends or storage costs (eg some tech stocks, and commodities like gold with low ratios of storage cost to value) that discount factor is approximately 1 and is omitted. That's why it can look like growth is being ignored even though it isn't.

    Inflation doesn't need to be explicitly accounted for in pricing options because it is automatically incorporated into the interest rate and hence also the expected growth rate.

    alan2

    But of course, we know that option pricing doesn't actually work. Just like MPT and CAPM it is fun math but it doesn't reflect reality.It depends what is meant by 'work'. Banks around the world use option pricing techniques like Black-Scholes to set prices for the hedging deals they offer their business customers, and they make consistent big profits with it. Usually it's a good predictor. But like all models, there are rare circumstances where it breaks down, and that's where one can lose big money. Long-Term Capital Management was a famous case of that.

  14. andrewkirk says:

    I like the approach of providing intuition by describing how the model works for a very short-term option, so that discounting can be ignored. That makes it a lot easier to grasp.

    The para that deals with interest rates (it starts with 'The prevailing interest rate should figure in these computations') is not quite right. The interest rate is the most complex part of the calculation. It is where the concept of changing the measure using the Cameron-Martin-Girsanov theorem comes in. It involves advanced concepts like equivalent martingale measures. So I would not say it is easily taken care of. The way to choose the interest rate is quite nuanced, and it affects not only the discounting of cash flows but also the assumed growth rate for the underlying stock, which determines how the mean of the bell curve shifts rightwards based on the time to option expiry. In the short-term example the bell curve does not shift at all, because the term to expiry is short enough to ignore expected growth.

    You could deal with that by writing a para something like:

    'In the above examples we have ignored interest rates and expected growth of the stock, because they will not be significant over a short period. For most options these need to be taken into account, and that is where the additional complexity comes in. But the principle is the same as in the above examples: measuring the expected payoff over a bell curve based on the final stock price.'

    • rude man says:

      The Black-Scholes model also ignores expected growth, at least the on-line calculators do. I suppose that is one reason why the full Blk-Sch model is so much more complex. Barring growth I see nothing wrong with using present value to take care of interest. Also, no one else seems to take inflation into account which nowadays is a much greater cost determinant than the short-term, safe interest rate.

      The other thing I omitted was of course dividends. This is a real problem since ex-dividend stock prices typically plunge. I don’t know if Black-Scholes deals with that. Anyway, as I tried to emphasize, I was not trying to out-gun Blk.-Sch., just trying to help people see the big picture.

      Thanks for your expert comment!

Leave a Reply

Want to join the discussion?
Feel free to contribute!

Leave a Reply