- #36
talk2glenn
brainstorm said:Price inflation actually discourages consumption. Do you want to buy more of something when the price goes up?
This is wrong. Inflation rates are, by definition,a function of change in price over time, and are typically quoted at an annualized rate. If you believe prices will be 4% higher this time next year than they are today, are you more or less likely to put off discretionary demand? On the other hand, if you believe prices will be lower this time next year, how does this affect your calculus?
If we assume that price levels must either be constant, increasing, or decreasing over time, and we further assume that consumption is a desirable economic outcome (that is, nobody benefits when you produce something, but don't trade it on the market), then it follows that price inflation is preferable, because it encourages consumption and discourages saving.
It is true that, at a fixed moment in time, consumers prefer lower to higher prices. The inflation rate in a fixed period is zero or more accurately irrelevant, however.
There may be some people who got some utility out of these things. They were just an example of something that many people did not really get any utility out of. I am suggesting that this is a general trend in a high-growth economy. In that case, many people would be working harder to keep up with consumption trends and pay off the debts accrued, while other people would be enjoying net income and profits due to those consumption trends.
Who benefits is irrelevant. The question is, given scarce resources, what distribution allocation maximizes aggregate utility? A competitive market, under every model, consistently (though, depending on the model and the desired outcome, not exclusively) achieves the most efficient result. Not everyone wins in a competitive environment, however. The losers tend to complain, and demand non-competitive intervention. This benefits these individuals, to the detriment of others and/or the whole (someone loses so that somebody else can gain - in economics we call this a Pareto inefficiency).
It also needs to be understood how marketing and other factors causes people to consume with the hope of gaining happiness without actually wanting the goods and services they are buying.
No, it does not. No rational individual is convinced to buy something they don't want by marketers. Marketing is defined as convincing consumers that your product satisfies a demand they already have. Marketers don't create the demand; they match specific products to specific needs.
This is the result of associations between immaterial things like happiness, peace of mind, friendship, and love and material commodities that are supposed to bring them. In reality, the high GDP economy is what is repressing these non-material commodities by reducing people's free time and ability to devote time and energy to non-material aspects of their lives.
This is nonsensical. Compare the lifestyles of individuals in high-GDP to low-GDP economies. It is absolutely true, without exception, that "wealthy" individuals have more free time than "poor" ones. By definition, the more you make per hour (GDP per capita per hour), the fewer hours you need to be productive to meet your staple demand. This leaves you with an increased number of hours to divide between leisure time and pursuit of discretionary demand.
It is a farce to suggest that individuals in wealthier economies are "slaves to consumption". Wealth is, and always has been, a liberating mechanism. Modern market economies create wealth more efficiently, and distribute that wealth more equitably, than any social systems in human history.
This reproduces the same effect of a high GDP economy, only in a more aggressive way. The issue is how a stable economy can emerge with low or negative GDP growth where competition to increase share of GDP gives way to adaptations to achieve economic well-being with less consumption and earning. Theoretically, both private consumers and businesses should be able to adapt their operations to adjust to lower GDP, deflation, etc. and maintain non-disasterous levels of production and consumption - but how?
Of course people could adapt to a lower GDP environment. The how is not mysterious or alien. GDP is a dollar measure of purchasing power. Less GDP means less purchasing power; poor people need to work harder to afford less.